Skip to content

All of the recent discussion of fiscal stimulus is very disappointing to an economist and deficit hawk like me. I'll ask two questions in this post and highlight them in bold.

Over the past few years, cheap credit and imprudent lending policies by some bad actors generated excessive consumption and investment in the real estate sector. This boosted economic activity beyond the level that would have prevailed with policies that we now wish, with hindsight, had been in place. That level of economic activity is the starting point for discussion of a recession, defined as two consecutive quarters of negative growth in real GDP. If we acknowledge that bad loans fueled the activity, why is it now a widely shared policy objective to maintain that level of activity?

The buzzwords for the stimulus discussion are that whatever the government does, it should be "timely, targeted, and temporary." Much of the discussion centers on a tax rebate, which would primarily boost consumption. Treasury Secretary Paulson is quoted as follows:

Asked if tax rebates to individuals - reportedly one of the cornerstones to the stimulus plan - is an effective course, Paulson said, “the evidence from [the] 2001 [rebate] was that people spent between a third and two-thirds of the money and spent it quickly, so the lesson here is we need to move quickly and do something in enough size.”

Forget the "stimulus" label, this is merely additional deficit spending. There is no discussion of repaying the money through higher taxes in the near term. Based on the President's remarks this morning, the deficit bill will be for about $150 billion. So this proposal is just another $150 billion of some future generations' resources that we will be using for our own consumption today. Why are we entitled to pass them this additional debt?

My views of how the government should conduct fiscal policy are presented here. We should expect some cyclical widening of the deficit with no change in policy. But if we have no intention of balancing the budget over the business cycle (i.e., of running an additional $150 billion surplus when the economy turns around), then we have no business pushing this deficit bill forward now.

UPDATE: Bruce Bartlett provides some background on tax rebates at the WSJ online and concludes:

A new rebate probably won't do much harm. But anyone who thinks it will prevent a recession -- if one is actually in the pipeline, which is not at all certain -- is dreaming. It's an insult to Keynes even to call a tax rebate Keynesian economics. It should be called "feel good economics" because its only real effect is to make politicians feel good about themselves and buy re-election with the public purse.

PGL at Angry Bear, reacting to the previous post, asks why stop with criticizing Governor Romney for his pandering? It's a reasonable question, but it has the standard economic answer--diminishing marginal returns to blogging about other people's mistakes.

Thinking a bit more about it, candidates deserve less slack when they make statements that are at odds with the personas they project in the campaign. Governor Romney campaigns specifically on his experience in the private sector and its contribution to economic growth. When he panders based on moving government resources to the aid of one particular constituency, that should be identified for what it is.

PGL then takes Governor Huckabee to task for, in the context of a question about lagging economic growth, advocating energy independence without acknowledging that any path to energy independence (e.g., a carbon tax) will reduce economic well-being in the near term. PGL is absolutely right. It's another answer that doesn't add up. But lots of people say silly things about energy independence, and this one didn't grab my attention.

McCain's answer to the question was better (some reasonably straight talk about the jobs not coming back and the need for retraining opportunities). Giuliani's was awful. Thompson's answer defended Giuliani's awful answer. Ron Paul's was probably the best. Read the whole transcript here--this is the first question to each candidate. What I liked about Paul's answer was that, in the course of his rambling answer, he said:

The recession has been predictable. We just don't know exactly when it will come.

If you do the wrong thing, it's going to last for a long time. The boom period comes when they just pour out easy credit and it teaches people to do the wrong things. There's a lot of malinvestment, debt that goes in the wrong direction, consumers who do the wrong things, and businessmen who do the wrong thing.

So we have to attack this and understand the importance of Austrian theory of the business cycle. If you don't, we're going to continue to do this and the longer you delay the recession, the worse the recession is, and we've delayed a serious recession for a long time.

The housing market's already in depression and a lot of people are hurt and the standing of living in this country is going down. Look at what's happening to the dollar.

And what is being offered by the Federal Reserve and Treasury and everybody in Washington? Lower interest rates. Well, lower interest rates is the problem. Artificially low interest rates is the artificial stimulus which causes the bubble, which allows the inevitable recession to come.

So what we need to do is deal with monetary policy and not pretend that artificial stimulus by more spending is going to help. That won't do you one bit of good.

It isn't perfect, but it's pretty good. To be clear, more government spending will mechanically prop up the rate of GDP growth. As PGL notes, given the way we do budgeting in this country, that means our kids will be paying (through a higher government debt burden) for our desire to avoid a slowdown in GDP growth. Why are we entitled to their money to clean up our housing mess?

The dollar, that's for sure. Even with the Loonie. A new low against the Euro. Paul Krugman asks if this is the Wile E. Coyote moment. I have a general view about what happens to the economies of large countries.

In almost all cases, the sky is not falling. Prices adjust so that it hangs lower and grayer.

Expect the dollar to decline until the U.S. current account imbalances shrink substantially. Expect some of this decline to happen as major exporting countries become less willing to organize themselves around holding dollars in exchange for their goods. Expect these countries to diversify their new investments and some of their existing ones, but not to dump their dollar holdings. No other country's short-term economic interests are served by devaluing its own asset holdings, and no exporting country's long-term economic interests are served by inviting a nationalistic, political response from the U.S.

At the end of May, the American Enterprise Institute held a panel discussion with the same title as the post. Here's a summary. It's an odd way to pose the question--if the focus is the global economy, rather than the U.S. economy, then why would a reduction in the price of goods and services purchased by those outside the U.S. economy be a threat? Normally, we would think that lower prices would be welcome.

Among the panelists, my views seem to be closest to Anne Krueger's, though I am less of an optimist about productivity growth. From the summary:

The focus on the current accounts deficit and falling dollar should not overshadow more pressing concerns. Prospective problems include the low savings rate, public education, and the fiscal deficit.

Read/hear/watch the whole thing.

The trip to Hawaii wasn't all vacation. The impetus for the trip was an invitation to make a presentation to a financial audience on "Economic Challenges: What Have We Learned? What Do We Face?" Here are the slides.

In a nutshell:

I identified three challenges to the U.S. economy that I think are fundamental: low and declining saving in all sectors of the economy, a declining labor force, and a dwindling labor income tax base. In all cases, the challenges make us less capable of absorbing additional pressures, whether unforeseen events in the near term or emerging pressures from population aging and the growth of health care costs persistently in excess of the economy's growth (and their interaction through the government's entitlement programs).

My prognosis:

Absent more prudent behavior, prices—exchange rates and interest rates—will simply change to equilibrate imbalances. The dollar has started to depreciate, but to me, the biggest mystery in the economy is how the U.S. long-term interest rate can stay so low. I cannot see it remaining that way for long, and its rise will take the stock market and (what's left of) the housing market with it. (This is a fascinating chart that didn't make it into the presentation.)

But I’ve been saying this for a while. As an economist, I’m happy to be right, but usually even happier to be wrong.

Enjoy!

The Administration has released its updated economic forecast. The top line number--the annual rate of growth in real GDP--has been revised downward from 2.9 percent to 2.3 percent for the four quarters of 2007 (the prior forecast is here). The forecast is dated June 4, 2007, so it incorporates the latest news on GDP growth for the first quarter. This suggests that forecast is based on the view that we will return to 2.9 percent growth in the second through fourth quarters (since (1.006*1.029*1.029*1.029)^(1/4) is roughly 1.023). Here's the relevant excerpt:

The forecast revises the projection of real gross domestic product (GDP) down from 2.9 percent growth to 2.3 percent during the four quarters of 2007. This revision incorporates the slower growth that occurred in the first quarter of the year with the expectation that solid growth will resume for the rest of 2007. The economy has now experienced over five years of uninterrupted growth, averaging 2.9 percent per year since the expansion began in 2001. Real GDP is projected to grow at about the historic average in 2008 and for the remaining years of the forecast.

I doubt many people will see this forecast as "too pessimistic," but I'm almost three years removed from spending a lot of time following the macroeconomy. The next stop for this forecast is to be used as an input into the Mid-Session Review of the budget by Treasury and OMB. The projected budget deficit will widen, but we have to wait until July (usually) to find out how much.

In the wake of last week's market volatility, Senator Clinton made a speech on the floor of the Senate and sent a letter to Chairman Bernanke and Secretary Paulson. Greg Mankiw characterized one part, appropriately in my view, as xenophobic. PGL at AngryBear responded with other parts that were, in his view (and to a lesser extent, mine) appropriately critical of our current macroeconomic policies.

The main problem with Clinton's argument is that there is no particular connection between the amount of U.S. debt that China and Japan hold and what happened last week. Is she really saying that the U.S. market wouldn't have dropped after the Chinese market dropped if we ran a trade surplus with China? Or if we still ran a deficit but China's resulting portfolio holdings were in some other country's federal liabilities rather than ours? Our economy is connected to the Chinese economy via both current account and capital account transactions. We might want to be more mindful of the latter than we have been. But that doesn't mean that the high ownership of U.S. debt by China caused the transmission of price movements from China to the United States.

Read this excerpt and see if she actually justifies the leap she makes in going from the red to the blue sentences below:

I have long argued that a great source of vulnerability is the fact that other countries, including China, own so much of our debt. Today, foreign nations according to the most recent Treasury statistics hold over $2.2 trillion or 44% of all publicly held United States (U.S.) debt with Japan and China alone holding nearly $1 trillion. In essence, 16% of our entire economy is being loaned to us by the Central Banks of other nations. Having so much debt owned by other countries can be economically unsound. Yesterday it was the sell off of foreign stocks that had reverberations in U.S. markets. But if China or Japan made a decision to decrease their massive holdings of U.S. dollars, there could be a currency crisis and the U.S. would have to raise interest rates and invite conditions for a recession. While it can and will be debated whether yesterday's market disruption was just a blip or a larger indicator of our economy's vulnerabilities, it is clear that interdependence between our economy and that of other nations can pose a risk if we do not pursue smart policies. Precipitous decisions by any country with our debt could create much graver economic problems than what we saw yesterday. The writing may not be on the wall, but yesterday, the writing was on the Big Board.

Her "in essence" sentence is not a sensible comparison. It does not make sense to compare a stock of money--the total holdings of U.S. federal debt by foreign investors--with the flow of money that is U.S. GDP. A sensible comparison might be the flow of interest that we pay to these foreign investors, a much smaller number as a share of GDP. (For example, I don't get too worried about the fact that a bank has lent me more than 100% of my income in the form of a mortgage. The reason is that the interest on that mortgage is a very reasonable fraction of my income.)

The statement in green above is a true statement. Not only would the problems be more grave--they might actually be problems and be related to what the creditor nations did. But even this scenario that she discusses is, in Mankiw's word, alarmist. There would have to be a reason why China or Japan would intentionally precipitate a selloff of their holdings of U.S. debt, particularly since the Chinese and Japanese holders of the debt would be the first ones to suffer the capital loss due to this action. It couldn't simply be that their own economies faltered--the U.S. debt they hold is an asset to them. When my income falters, I am typically quite grateful for the assets I have in the bank (somebody else's liabilities). Their economies would have to falter so badly that they needed to liquidate their holdings of U.S. debt to pay off some of their own debts. Not too likely, unless, perhaps, we close our markets to them.

Clinton's rhetoric, particularly these statements about being "held hostage" or "losing our economic sovereignty," suggest that she's thinking about a scenario in which a policy maker in Beijing or Tokyo decides that the U.S. debt is overvalued and wants to unload it en masse. About the only thing that could really convince me to do this, were I the policy maker in Beijing, is a credible belief that my counterpart in Tokyo was about to do the same thing.

While that is something over which Washington has very little control, even in that case, all that would happen--unless you think the U.S. government wouldn't pay the interest or principal on its obligations--is that the U.S. dollar would depreciate and domestic interest rates would rise. Exports would pick up a bit, and the government would find deficits more costly to finance. I'd prefer if that didn't happen, but in the grand scheme of things, it's neither very likely to happen nor very severe in its real consequences if it does.

Barry Ritholz wonders today about the spike in his blog's traffic yesterday as markets around the world were losing value. I admit that I contributed to his site's traffic as I used these three posts to explain to my undergraduate finance theory students how to try to make sense of large market movements. We are passed the lectures on bubbles, noise trading, and herd behavior, and so we spent only a little time assessing what occurred.

In the first of these linked posts, Barry contrasts the explanation based on China's 8.8% drop with other events that also occurred yesterday, including news stories related to subprime lending and the weakness in the Advanced Durable Goods report. I don't buy any explanation based on China--its stock market is too small, the effect on other Asian markets was not particularly large, and weakness in the Chinese economy would indicate that we are likely to be able to run our trade deficit with China at lower cost. That shouldn't be bad news. I don't know enough about the subprime lending issues to know how important they were--I think it's a fairly marginal part of the real housing sector, so I'm skeptical there as well.

That would leave us with the weakness in durable goods. If this is to be the explanation, then it is interesting that it generated a downward movement. Typically, when there is unexpected strength in the other major monthly economic releases like GDP and Employment, the market does poorly. The rationale is that unexpected strength in the economy will make the odds of a Fed increase in short term interest rates more likely. That increase, in turn, depresses stock market values. The same process, probably to a milder extent, should operate in reverse for unexpected weakness in the macroeconomy.

So this durable goods report was unexpected weakness--why didn't the market hold steady or even go up? According to this view, the answer would have to be that, unlike GDP and Employment, the Durable Goods report also tells us directly about economy-wide investment and thus future business growth. So weakness there could be greeted not just with the lower inflationary expectations but lower profit expectations as well. Plausible--a good event study to do for an undergraduate finance major, perhaps.

My preferred explanation is that we have plenty of investors, both individual and institutional, who treat stock markets like a speculative exercise. There is noise trading and herd behavior aplenty, and so a drop of over 3% in the U.S., and larger drops in more thinly traded markets, shouldn't be all that surprising. I didn't even check my portfolios yesterday.

Via the Opinionator, here are some anecdotes from Daniel Gross about the way some professional investors in China viewed the events:

Special World is Flat bonus anecdote. Note the way Chinese analysts have quickly assimilated the technique, developed over several decades by U.S. analysts, of using fatuous cliches to explain baffling market activity.

''The most important reason for today's decline was pressure for profit-taking,'' said Peng Yunliang, a senior analyst at Shanghai Securities.

''People viewed 3,000 as a psychological benchmark. It's understandable they might want to pull back after the market hit that peak,'' Peng added.

It truly is a global capital market.

My quick read of the just released January employment report is that the main indicators were partly up and partly down. We saw some improvement in payroll jobs (+111,000) with unemployment rates holding steady around 4.6 percent and hours and average weekly earnings slightly down.

January is the month in which the BLS revises its jobs numbers to better match the sample's underlying population drawn from unemployment insurance records. The result in this case is that there were an additional 933,000 payroll jobs at the end of December 2006 than previously estimated. (See the discussion regarding "Table B" in the report.) So combined with the 111,000 net new jobs in January, I expect that most of the news coverage will focus on these "additional 1 million jobs." You are likely to hear the phrase "8.2 million new jobs since August 2003" quite a lot, based on an update to these talking points.

UPDATE: My mistake--the 7.4 million new jobs in the talking points noted above already had the adjustments had already been factored in. Very smart folks.